Boston Review, Summer 2002, pp. 4, 14
[To see the Bollier piece
and the other responses, go to:
http://bostonreview.mit.edu]
1. Bollier reminds us that many aspects of our society and economy, of great significance to individual and community life, serve us less well when operated to maximize profit for private owners.
2. He offers us the concept of the “commons” as a way of understanding both our needs and the ways in which those needs are compromised by private ownership.
Most readers of Boston Review will probably agree with Bollier's first point.
Most will also likely recognize the concept of commons and sometimes find it useful in this context.
My concern is that stretching the rubber band of “commons” around the range of issues he covers causes it to snap. That renders it less useful in holding together the arguments it can contain.
Bollier offers four case studies. I largely agree with the philosophy, policy and politics underlying his discussion. I am currently writing about the pharmaceutical industry in words consistent with those of Bollier, and have come to conclude that the industry’s behavior is so egregious in supplying essential goods that we simply must consider its nationalization. Since my appointment as an FCC Commissioner in 1966, I have voiced concerns similar to Bollier’s about the public interest responsibilities of broadcasters.
With regard to the Internet, I find Lawrence Lessig’s book, The Future of Ideas (which Bollier cites), to be a useful text in my Cyberspace Law Seminar. Moreover, on my web site, I attempt to practice what he and Bollier preach: anyone can download hundreds of my articles, even a couple of books, for free. On the question of children, I have never liked Jonathan Swift’s suggestion that we eat them. So I agree with Bollier about that as well.
Bollier and I agree less, however, about the utility of the commons framework in analyzing these, and related, issues.
Federal subsidies as commons
Massive campaign contributions can bring corporate donors returns of one thousand to one or more from government action. The pharmaceutical industry is an outrageous example. But is it helpful to say that all private recipients of federal money “steal the goose from off the common”?
You and I may not like our elected representatives’ decisions, but unless we’re willing to challenge Winston Churchill’s conclusion (“democracy is the worst form of government except for all the others”) we’re stuck with them. With the exception of our current president, each was elected by a majority of the voters. Their decisions are what our system produces.
Broadcasting as commons
One can argue, as broadcasters do, that the “airwaves” are no more a commons, and no more scarce, than land – which is mostly held in private ownership. Bollier and I disagree with the broadcasters.
But however one comes out on that electrical engineering diversion, broadcasting involves much more than a commons analysis can provide. As the duck says in the movie Babe with regard to the prohibition on pigs in houses, “That’s a good rule. I like that rule. But this is bigger than rules.”
Isn’t our real concern about broadcasting the central role of its content in the democratic process? If so, to put emphasis on broadcasting’s largely obsolete “commons” technology is to give away the arguments regarding the importance of all media and all means of distribution.
Nor are ownership limitations the solution. If ten thousand broadcast stations were separately owned by ten thousand profit-maximizing Republican Rotarians there wouldn’t be much more programming diversity than if all were owned by one.
What would produce diversity would be a total separation of content from conduit in all media. (You can own the programming, or the cable system, but not both.) Or, a requirement of at least some right of paid entry into all near-monopoly media. (Newspapers couldn’t refuse every paid ad they disagreed with.)
Internet as commons
The pre-divestiture AT&T was a kind of conduit-only commons. No one could be refused a phone. And AT&T didn’t censor content. As a result, few First Amendment complaints were lodged against this Goliath monopolist.
The Internet is kind of like that. Or at least it was. Here “commons” is helpful. And I agree with Bollier (and Lessig) that it’s under attack from the corporate thief “that steals the common from the goose.”
Children as commons
Do children in the U.S. get the public policy regard provided by civilized nations? No. Are they commercially exploited? Absolutely. Must we, can we, do better. Of course. Do we have a common interest in our community’s children? Yes. (It takes a child to raise a village.) But the idea that children are usefully thought of as a "commons" seems abstract and strained. The commons framework is more appropriately applied to air, water, public lands and public domain intellectual property. I don’t find it useful with children’s issues.
Nevertheless, “Reclaiming
the Commons” shouts a warning all need to hear. And if we don’t start talking
about the privatization of our media today, we are likely to discover that
we can no longer talk about much of anything that matters tomorrow.
_______________
Nicholas Johnson, a former FCC Commissioner and recovering school board member, teaches law at University of Iowa.
Nicholas Johnson on David
Bollier’s “Reclaiming the Commons”
Boston Review
July 2002
20020614 2230 #3 854 words
David Bollier offers us at least two contributions.
1. He reminds us that there are a number of aspects of our society and economy, of great significance to our individual and community life, that serve us less well when operated to maximize profit for private owners.
2. He offers us the concept of the “commons” as a way of understanding both our needs and the ways in which those needs are compromised by private ownership.
Most readers of the Boston Review would agree with his first point.
Most would also recognize the concept of commons, and sometimes find it useful in this context.
My concern is that stretching the rubber band of “commons” around even the issues he covers (let alone those for which none of us have space) causes it to snap. That only renders it less useful in holding together the arguments it can contain.
He offers four case studies. There is little in the philosophy, policy and politics he reveals with which I disagree:
1. Pharmaceuticals. I am currently writing about the pharmaceutical industry in words consistent with those of Bollier. This industry’s behavior is so egregious in supplying essential goods that we simply must consider its nationalization.
2. Broadcasting. Since appointment as an FCC Commissioner in 1966 my mantra has echoed Bollier’s concerns about the public interest responsibilities of broadcasters.
3. Internet. I use Lawrence Lessig’s book, The Future of Ideas (which Bollier cites), as a text in my Cyberspace Law Seminar at Iowa. Moreover, on my Web site, www.nicholasjohnson.org, I practice what he and Bollier preach: anyone can download hundreds of my articles, even a couple of books, for free.
4. Children. So far as I can recall, I have never been quoted in support of Jonathan Swift’s suggestion that we eat our children. So we agree about that as well.
There is less agreement between us about the utility of “commons” in analyzing these, and related, issues.
Government Subsidies as Commons
Massive campaign contributions can bring corporate donors returns of 1000 or 2000-to-one from government action. That’s true. The pharmaceutical industry is an outrageous example. But is it helpful to say that all private recipients of federal money “steal the goose from off the common” (to borrow from Bollier’s opening English folk poem)?
You and I may not like our elected representatives’ decisions, but unless we’re willing to challenge Winston Churchill’s conclusion (“democracy is the worst form of government except for all the others”) we’re stuck with them. With the exception of our current president, each was elected by a majority of the voters. Their decisions are what our system produces.
Broadcasting As Commons
One can argue, as broadcasters do, that the “airwaves” are no more a commons, and no more scarce, than land – which is mostly held in private ownership. Bollier and I disagree with the broadcasters.
But however one comes out on that electrical engineering diversion, broadcasting involves much more than a commons analysis can provide. As the duck says in the movie “Babe” with regard to the prohibition on pigs in houses, “That’s a good rule. I like that rule. But this is bigger than rules.”
Isn’t our real concern about
broadcasting the central role of its content in the democratic process?
If so, to put emphasis on broadcasting’s largely obsolete “commons” technology
is to give away the arguments regarding the importance of all media and
all means of distribution.
Nor are ownership limitations
the solution. If 10,000 broadcast stations were separately owned by 10,000
profit-maximizing Republican Rotarians there wouldn’t be much more programming
diversity than if all were owned by one.
What would produce diversity would be a total separation of content from conduit in all media. (You can own the programming, or the cable system, but not both.) Or, a requirement of at least some right of paid entry into all near-monopoly media. (Newspapers couldn’t refuse every paid ad they disagreed with.)
Internet as Commons
The pre-divestiture AT&T was a kind of conduit-only commons. No one could be refused a phone. And AT&T didn’t censor content. As a result few First Amendment complaints were lodged against this Goliath monopolist.
The Internet’s kind of like that. Or at least it was. Here “commons” is helpful. And I agree with Bollier (and Lessig) that it’s under attack from, again to borrow from the folk poem, the corporation “that steals the common from the goose.”
Children as Commons
Do children in the U.S. get the public policy regard provided by civilized nations? No. Are they commercially exploited? Absolutely. Must we, can we, do better. Of course. Do we have a common interest in our community’s children (“it takes a child to raise a village”)? Yes.
For me, “commons” works as a concept for air, water, public lands and public domain intellectual property. I don’t find it useful with children’s issues.
“Reclaiming the Commons,” like Bollier’s book, Silent Theft, shouts a warning all need to hear. And if we don’t start talking about the privatization of our media today we are likely to discover that we can no longer talk about much of anything that matters tomorrow.